Dvara Research BlogDvara Research Blog
Dvara Research Blog
Doorway to Financial Access
  • Home
  • Our Work
  • Themes
  • Subscribe
    • Email Subscription
    • Feed
  • Contact Us
Menu back  

Universal Health Coverage through Statutory Health Insurance in Germany

September 20, 2021Leave a commentResearch Viewed : 952

By Anjali Nambiar, Dvara Research

Germany was the first country to introduce social health insurance at the national level. Its statutory health insurance system has developed and evolved significantly since its inception as a Bismarckian model (to be explained later), through the course of time to its adoption of principles of competition. Backed by one of the highest total expenditures in health among OECD countries (see Table 1), it has provided health coverage to 100% of its population. While its DALY rate is comparatively high, it has low infant and maternal mortality rates. In this post, we analyse the SHI system and its role in universal health coverage, while acknowledging the role of solidarity in its foundation.

Table 1: Health system indicators in OECD countries

CountryTotal Health ExpenditureGovt. shareUnder 5-MRDALY rateMaternal Mortality Rate
Australia$ 4,91968.7%3.625598.66
France$ 5,27483.7%4.527289.28
Germany$ 6,73185.1%3.832162.27
Israel$ 2,90364.8%3.719702.23
Sweden$ 5,75485.1%2.626888.14
Switzerland$ 7,13866.8%4.025581.35
United Kingdom$ 5,26881.7%4.329324.87
United States$ 10,94882.7%6.533866.319

Note: The values above are the latest available figures for each country (2019/2020)

Statutory Health Insurance System

The Statutory Health Insurance (SHI) system is a mandatory[1], contribution-based system providing health risk cover through an exhaustive benefits package which includes diagnosis, ambulatory (outpatient) care, and inpatient treatment along with prevention and health promotion initiatives at the workplace. Consumers can choose among the 105 not-for-profit sickness funds and are allowed to switch every 18 months.

The system is marked by its self-governed nature with associations at the municipal, state and federal level. Negotiations over prices and services occur among the regional associations of physicians (SHI employed), providers and sickness funds. The sickness funds sign collective contracts with regional associations of ambulatory physicians, dentists and hospitals. Federal associations represent these regional associations at the national level. The fracturing of outpatient care (ambulatory physicians) from inpatient care (hospitals) is the result of a political compromise which came in response to the conflicts between office-based doctors and sickness funds. Initially, it created the system of joint self-governance characterised by regional associations and collective negotiation. Later, the physicians lobbied and successfully obtained a monopoly over out-patient services and essentially split this service from hospitals which then confined themselves to inpatient care. This development remains a drawback in the present, impairing coordination within the health system which is especially important in the case of chronic diseases. The introduction of disease management programs[2]  and integrated care programs (explained later) were aimed at filling this gap in the SHI system.

Mandatory wage-related contributions and supplementary contributions from employers and employees are the primary source of funding for the system, supplemented by tax-financed budget subsidies (see Figure 1). The contributions are collected by the sickness funds and transferred to the Central Reallocation Pool (Gesundheitsfonds) to be pooled with the government subsidies. Allocation of funds from the pool to the sickness funds occurs in a morbidity-based risk adjusted scheme[3] (Morbi-RSA). Such adjustment is used to disincentivise risk selection by sickness funds.

Figure 1: Financing Flow in the SHI System

The Morbi-RSA scheme provides capitated payments to sickness funds which in turn pay the physicians on a fee-for-service (FFS) basis and hospitals on a diagnosis-related group (DRG) basis (Figure 1).  FFS payments can induce moral hazard in providers (over-provision) since they get paid for each service provided. However, it is also to be noted that the inclusion of preventive care services in the SHI benefit package (in 2000) was followed by an increase in the primary preventive care spending from €1.10 to €4.33 per person covered by SHI between 2000 and 2010. Such increased use of preventive services would augur well for both consumers and sickness funds in terms of reduced curative healthcare costs in the future.

The DRG payment model is outcome focused[4] and incentivises cost control but can also lead to benefits denial and risk selection as healthier patients within a disease category are preferred in order to control costs. Moreover, geographic risk selection can still occur since it is easily determined and not adjusted for in the Morbi-RSA scheme. This “cream skimming” has been observed as sickness funds avoid patients from high-cost regions by avoiding their customer service calls.  Therefore, an incentive for risk selection can persist despite the presence of risk adjustment mechanisms. A recently passed (February 2020) regulation has now added a regional component to the list of risk adjusters under SHI.

Since sickness funds are paid on a capitated basis, they usually cannot change their prices to provide value-added services. Consequently, funds were allowed to create tariff structures in 2007 to provide differential charges like higher co-sharing arrangements to attract wealthy, low risk consumers. Cost-sharing arrangements in the form of co-pays and co-insurance are levied to prevent moral hazard. Consumers can also cover these payments by availing supplementary private health insurance (PHI).

While the prices for these payment models are negotiated at the association level (collective contracting), selective contracting was introduced as an option in 2000, which marked the beginning of integrated models within the SHI system.

Figure 2: Integrated Care Program

Integrated Care Programs (ICPs) were introduced as one of the reforms aimed at cross-sectoral cooperation and fostering competition to improve quality through managed care. SHI sickness funds can participate in such ICPs to provide coordinated care to their members in addition to the standard benefits provided under SHI. The initial formation of ICPs occurred through a two-step process (Figure 2). Providers came together to form an integrated care network (ICN) which then contracted with a payer i.e. sickness fund through an integrated care contract (ICC).  The flexibility to choose the payment method in such contracts has given rise to FFS, capitation and pay for performance (P4P) models. While the providers continue to be paid under the FFS system by SHI, the additional services under the ICP are paid through one of these models[5]. Why such varied payment models were deemed necessary for the add-on services and what incentives they sought to promote, are questions that require further research. The physicians in such networks can also act as gate-keepers to specialists, a feature otherwise absent in the SHI system. The general physicians hence guide the patient in the fragmented healthcare system improving coordination of care.  The thrust on preventive and promotive care in such programs is beneficial to members’ wellbeing and helps in cost containment for the funds.

Evolution and Reforms in the System

Contextual factors, mainly political, have shaped the features and functioning of the SHI system since its introduction to its current state. Chancellor Otto von Bismarck established the Social Health Insurance (SHI) system in 1883 along the lines of solidarity with its decentralised structure, contributions according to ability to pay, provision according to need and shared contributions with employers. Such a universal, mandatory health system came to be known as the Bismarckian model of health insurance. It built on previously existing sickness fund structures like industrial workers’ mutual-aid organisations and company-based mutual schemes and gradually increased coverage by including more classes of workers. Eventually mandatory SHI supplemented by PHI and other specific government schemes aided in achieving universal health coverage.

After the inception of the system in 1883, it has undergone multiple reforms over the years to control costs and improve quality through competition. An important reform was the introduction of the option of selective contracting (ICPs) which was later supplemented by start-up funding in 2004. Another measure geared at stimulating competition was the introduction of free choice to consumers in 1993 wherein they could enrol in any of the sickness funds as opposed to their options being restricted to those funds that were affiliated with the association in their region.

Conclusion

Germany’s SHI system provides multiple lessons for health systems design. Its decentralised nature with regional associations facilitates negotiations among representatives of the stakeholders. While collective contracting through such associations remains the overarching feature of the system, it has evolved through government intervention. The role of regulation has been instrumental in introducing integration and supporting its growth through government sponsorship. Furthermore, it seeks to learn from the limitations of collective contracting to make room for innovative payment models to incentivise provision of coordinated and quality healthcare.

References

Amelung, V., Hildebrandt, H., & Wolf, S. (2012). Integrated care in Germany—A stony but necessary road! International Journal of Integrated Care, 12, e16.

Bauhoff, S. (2012). Do Health Plans Risk-Select? An Audit Study on Germany’s Social Health Insurance (SSRN Scholarly Paper ID 2170664). Social Science Research Network. https://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=2170664

Blumel, M., & Busse, R. (2020). International Health Care System Profiles—Germany. The Commonwealth Fund. https://www.commonwealthfund.org/international-health-policy-center/countries/germany

Blumel, M., Spranger, A., Achstetter, K., Maresso, A., & Busse, R. (2020). Germany: Health system review 2020. European Health Observatory/World Health Organisation,22(6). https://eurohealthobservatory.who.int/publications/i/germany-health-system-review-2020

Busse, R., Blümel, M., Knieps, F., & Bärnighausen, T. (2017). Statutory health insurance in Germany: A health system shaped by 135 years of solidarity, self-governance, and competition. The Lancet, 390(10097), 882–897. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0140-6736(17)31280-1

European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. (2013). Eurohealth: Incentivising integrated care. Eurohealth, 19(2). https://apps.who.int/iris/handle/10665/332867

Gottret, P., & Schieber, G. (2006). Health Financing Revisited: A Practitioner’s Guide. World Bank. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/7094

Institute for Health Metrics and Evaluation. (2021). GBD Results Tool. Global Health Data Exchange. http://ghdx.healthdata.org/gbd-results-tool

Milstein, R., & Blankart, C. R. (2016a). Special Care in Germany. OECD. https://www.oecd.org/els/health-systems/Better-Ways-to-Pay-for-Health-Care-Background-Note-Germany.pdf

Milstein, R., & Blankart, C. R. (2016b). The Health Care Strengthening Act: The next level of integrated care in Germany. Health Policy, 120(5), 445–451. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.healthpol.2016.04.006

OECD. (n.d.). Health resources—Health spending—OECD Data. OECD. Retrieved August 12, 2021, from http://data.oecd.org/healthres/health-spending.htm

OECD. (2019). Germany: Country Health Profile 2019. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. https://www.oecd.org/publications/germany-country-health-profile-2019-36e21650-en.htm

Paglione, L., Baccolini, V., Marceca, M., & Villari, P. (2018). The Governance of Prevention in Germany. The Governance of Prevention in Germany, 2018-vol. 3. https://doi.org/10.19252/0000000AC

Roberts, M., Hsiao, W., Berman, P., & Reich, M. (2008). Getting Health Reform Right: A Guide to Improving Performance and Equity. Oxford University Press. https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:oso/9780195371505.001.0001

World Bank. (2021a). Life expectancy at birth, total (years) | Data. The World Bank. https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SP.DYN.LE00.IN

World Bank. (2021b). Mortality rate, under-5 (per 1,000 live births) | Data. https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SH.DYN.MORT

World Bank. (2021c). Maternal mortality ratio (modeled estimate, per 100,000 live births) | Data. https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SH.STA.MMRT


[1] Employees whose gross income exceeds the opt-out threshold can choose to avail private health insurance instead of SHI. Nevertheless, it is mandatory to be covered by health insurance, whether SHI, private or other schemes.

[2] Disease management programs create structured pathways especially for patients suffering from chronic diseases. Herein the physicians direct the consumers to the required care in the fragmented health system.

[3] This scheme was an improvement over the previous risk adjustment scheme (along the lines of age, gender and invalidity status) since it subsidises the sickness funds for the real morbidity risks arising from these risks as well as pre-existing diseases of its consumers.

[4] The providers are paid a fixed amount for each disease placing the onus on the hospital to reduce unnecessary costs and optimise treatment procedures.

[5] One such ICP, Gesundes Kinzigtal was formed by two sickness funds that signed a contract with a network of providers to offer such integrated care to their members free of cost. It has an innovative payment model where providers are paid P4P for services provided and bonus sums for meeting targets (patient compliance, regular diagnosis) and providers also share profits with the sickness fund from saved costs.


Cite this Item

MLA

(Nambiar, Universal Health Coverage through Statutory Health Insurance in Germany 2021)

APA

(Nambiar, Universal Health Coverage through Statutory Health Insurance in Germany)

Chicago

(Nambiar, Universal Health Coverage through Statutory Health Insurance in Germany)

Share Via :Tweet about this on Twitter
Twitter
Share on Facebook
Facebook
Share on LinkedIn
Linkedin
Email this to someone
email
Healthhealth careHealth Insurancehealth outcomesInsuranceSocial health insuranceSocial Protection InitiativeUniversal health coverage
Leave Comment

Cancel reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

You may use these HTML tags and attributes: <a href="" title=""> <abbr title=""> <acronym title=""> <b> <blockquote cite=""> <cite> <code> <del datetime=""> <em> <i> <q cite=""> <s> <strike> <strong>

nine − eight =

clear formSubmit

Related posts
Health Insurance Ownership in India
August 5, 2022
Managed Competition in the National Health Insurance System of Israel
July 25, 2022
NSSO’s latest Debt and Investment survey points to significant disparities in net worth among Indian households
July 20, 2022
Report: The costs of using Buy Now, Pay Later (BNPL) products
July 7, 2022
Towards designing UPI services for constrained users
July 6, 2022
Payment Failures in Direct Benefit Transfers
July 4, 2022
Search
Recent Comments
  • Prasanna Srinivasan on Care through competition: The case of the Netherlands: “This made interesting and informative reading. Thank you. Inevitably, the mind ran a comparison with the Indian context even while…”
  • Misha Sharma on Direct Benefit Transfers in Assam, Chhattisgarh, and Andhra Pradesh: Introducing the Dvara-Haqdarshak Study on Exclusion in Government to Person Payments: “Great post, Aarushi. It will also be interesting to document the challenges faced in accessing these transfers and experiences with…”
  • Misha Sharma on What is Social Protection?: “Thanks for writing this, Anupama. A much needed piece and looking forward to the second post in this series. It…”
Subscribe and Follow Us

Popular Post

Popular Post
  • Health Insurance Ownership in India
    August 5, 2022
  • Managed Competition in the National Health Insurance System of Israel
    July 25, 2022
  • NSSO’s latest Debt and Investment survey points to significant disparities in net worth among Indian households
    July 20, 2022

Categories

Categories
  • Channels(88)
  • Consumer Protection(33)
  • Events(30)
  • Featured(42)
  • Field Reports(6)
  • From the field(9)
  • General(22)
  • Guest(30)
  • Household Research(75)
  • Long Term Debt Markets(9)
  • News(45)
  • Origination(30)
  • Products(42)
  • Regulation(112)
  • Research(259)
  • Risk Aggregation(26)
  • Risk transmission(63)
  • Small Cities(21)
  • Technology(25)
  • Uncategorized(106)
  • Unemployment Support(5)

Archives

Archives
  • August 2022 (1)
  • July 2022 (5)
  • June 2022 (5)
  • May 2022 (2)
  • April 2022 (4)
  • March 2022 (2)
  • February 2022 (3)
  • January 2022 (3)
  • December 2021 (4)
  • November 2021 (6)
  • October 2021 (4)
  • September 2021 (4)
  • August 2021 (6)
  • July 2021 (6)
  • June 2021 (10)
  • May 2021 (7)
  • April 2021 (9)
  • March 2021 (9)
  • February 2021 (7)
  • January 2021 (3)
  • December 2020 (7)
  • November 2020 (6)
  • October 2020 (10)
  • September 2020 (9)
  • August 2020 (12)
  • July 2020 (3)
  • June 2020 (5)
  • May 2020 (8)
  • April 2020 (4)
  • March 2020 (8)
  • February 2020 (3)
  • January 2020 (9)
  • December 2019 (4)
  • November 2019 (3)
  • October 2019 (7)
  • September 2019 (3)
  • August 2019 (2)
  • July 2019 (4)
  • June 2019 (4)
  • May 2019 (4)
  • April 2019 (7)
  • March 2019 (2)
  • February 2019 (3)
  • January 2019 (3)
  • December 2018 (5)
  • November 2018 (2)
  • October 2018 (5)
  • September 2018 (2)
  • August 2018 (2)
  • July 2018 (2)
  • June 2018 (2)
  • May 2018 (1)
  • April 2018 (1)
  • March 2018 (5)
  • February 2018 (2)
  • January 2018 (2)
  • December 2017 (5)
  • November 2017 (4)
  • October 2017 (3)
  • September 2017 (1)
  • August 2017 (3)
  • July 2017 (1)
  • June 2017 (3)
  • May 2017 (4)
  • April 2017 (3)
  • March 2017 (4)
  • February 2017 (3)
  • January 2017 (6)
  • December 2016 (5)
  • November 2016 (2)
  • October 2016 (3)
  • September 2016 (5)
  • August 2016 (4)
  • July 2016 (4)
  • June 2016 (8)
  • May 2016 (4)
  • April 2016 (5)
  • March 2016 (4)
  • February 2016 (3)
  • January 2016 (3)
  • December 2015 (3)
  • November 2015 (1)
  • October 2015 (2)
  • September 2015 (3)
  • August 2015 (5)
  • July 2015 (3)
  • June 2015 (3)
  • May 2015 (3)
  • April 2015 (2)
  • March 2015 (3)
  • February 2015 (1)
  • January 2015 (1)
  • December 2014 (5)
  • November 2014 (4)
  • October 2014 (3)
  • September 2014 (4)
  • August 2014 (4)
  • July 2014 (4)
  • June 2014 (8)
  • May 2014 (1)
  • April 2014 (4)
  • March 2014 (5)
  • February 2014 (6)
  • January 2014 (8)
  • December 2013 (7)
  • November 2013 (8)
  • October 2013 (7)
  • September 2013 (7)
  • August 2013 (5)
  • July 2013 (6)
  • June 2013 (7)
  • May 2013 (6)
  • April 2013 (8)
  • March 2013 (9)
  • February 2013 (6)
  • January 2013 (9)
  • December 2012 (8)
  • November 2012 (7)
  • October 2012 (5)
  • September 2012 (5)
  • August 2012 (5)
  • July 2012 (7)
  • June 2012 (4)
  • May 2012 (6)
  • April 2012 (4)
  • March 2012 (7)
  • February 2012 (6)
  • January 2012 (8)
  • December 2011 (8)
  • November 2011 (7)
  • October 2011 (8)
  • September 2011 (7)
  • August 2011 (3)
  • July 2011 (6)
  • June 2011 (11)
  • May 2011 (8)
  • April 2011 (9)
  • March 2011 (13)
  • February 2011 (10)
  • January 2011 (8)
  • December 2010 (10)
  • November 2010 (10)
  • October 2010 (10)
  • September 2010 (7)
  • August 2010 (13)
  • July 2010 (10)
  • June 2010 (6)
  • May 2010 (13)
  • April 2010 (7)
  • March 2010 (10)
  • February 2010 (5)
  • January 2010 (4)
  • December 2009 (3)
  • November 2009 (1)
  • October 2009 (6)
  • August 2009 (1)
  • July 2009 (2)
  • June 2009 (1)
  • May 2009 (1)
  • April 2009 (1)
  • March 2009 (1)

Share Via :Tweet about this on Twitter

Twitter

Share on Facebook

Facebook

Share on LinkedIn

Linkedin

Email this to someone

email

Site Map

www.dvara.com